RC time constant: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
en>AlanM1
m Fixing style/layout errors
 
Line 1: Line 1:
[[Image:Contract-curve-on-edgeworth-box.svg|thumb|400px|right|Blue contract curve showing points of tangency of [[indifference curve]]s in an [[Edgeworth box]]]]
Roberto is [http://www.Google.com/search?q=what%27s+written&btnI=lucky what's written] located on his birth certificate  he never really adored that name. South Carolina is its birth place. The [http://Search.huffingtonpost.com/search?q=favourite+hobby&s_it=header_form_v1 favourite hobby] for him and moreover his kids is to fish and he's previously been doing it for a long time. Auditing is how he supports the puppy's family. Go of his website to come out more: http://circuspartypanama.com<br><br>Also visit my webpage clash of clans cheat, [http://circuspartypanama.com Highly recommended Site],
 
Any [[Walrasian equilibrium]] lies on the contract curve. As with all points that are Pareto efficient, each point on the contract curve is a point of tangency between an indifference curve of one person and an indifference curve of the other person. Thus, on the contract curve the [[marginal rate of substitution]] is the same for both people.
 
==Example==
Assume the existence of an economy with two agents, Octavio and Abby, who consume two goods X and Y of which there are fixed supplies, as illustrated in the above Edgeworth box diagram.  Further, assume an initial distribution (endowment) of the goods between Octavio and Abby and let each have normally structured (convex) preferences represented by [[indifference curves]] that are convex toward the people's respective origins. If the initial allocation is not at a point of tangency between an indifference curve of Octavio and one of Abby, then that initial allocation must be at a point where an indifference curve of Octavio crosses one of Abby. These two indifference curves form a lens shape, with the initial allocation at one of the two corners of the lens. Octavio and Abby will choose to make mutually beneficial trades — that is, they will trade to a point that is on a better (farther from the origin) indifference curve for both. Such a point will be in the interior of the lens, and the rate at which one good will be traded for the other will be between the marginal rate of substitution of Octavio and that of Abby. Since the trades will always provide each person with more of one good and less of the other, trading results in movement upward and to the left, or downward and to the right, in the diagram.
 
The two people will continue to trade so long as each one’s [[marginal rate of substitution]] (the absolute value of the slope of the person's indifference curve at that point) differs from that of the other person at the current allocation (in which case there will be a mutually acceptable trading ratio of one good for the other, between the different marginal rates of substitution). At a point where Octavios’s marginal rate of substitution equals Abby’s marginal rate of substitution, no more mutually beneficial exchange is possible.  This point is called a [[Pareto efficient]] equilibrium.  In the Edgeworth box, it is a point at which Octavio’s indifference curve is tangent to Abby’s indifference curve, and it is inside the lens formed by their initial allocations.  
 
Thus the contract curve, the set of points Octavio and Abby could end up at, is the section of the Pareto efficient locus that is in the interior of the lens formed by the initial allocations. The analysis cannot say which particular point along the contract curve they will end up at — this depends on the two people's bargaining skills.
 
==Mathematical Explanation==
In the case of two goods and two individuals, the contract curve can be found as follows. Here <math>x_{2}^{1}</math> refers to the final amount of good 2 allocated to person 1, etc., <math>u^1</math> and <math>u^2</math> refer to the final levels of utility experienced by person 1 and person 2 respectively, <math>u_{0}^{2}</math> refers to the level of utility that person 2 would receive from the initial allocation without trading at all, and <math>\omega_{1}^{tot}</math> and <math>\omega_{2}^{tot}</math> refer to the fixed total quantities available of goods 1 and 2 respectively.
 
:<math>\max_{x_{1}^{1},x_{2}^{1},x_{1}^{2},x_{2}^{2}} u^1(x_{1}^{1},x_{2}^{1})</math>
 
subject to:
 
:<math>
x_{1}^{1}+x_{1}^{2} \leq \omega_{1}^{tot}
</math>
 
:<math>
x_{2}^{1}+x_{2}^{2} \leq \omega_{2}^{tot}
</math>
 
:<math>
u^2(x_{1}^{2},x_{2}^{2}) \geq u_{0}^{2}
</math>
 
This optimization problem states that the goods are to be allocated between the two people in such a way that no more than the available amount of each good is allocated to the two people combined, and the first person's utility is to be as high as possible while making the second person's utility no lower than at the initial allocation (so the second person would not refuse to trade from the initial allocation to the point found); this formulation of the problem finds a Pareto efficient point on the  lens, as far as possible from person 1's origin. This is the point that would be achieved if person 1 had all the bargaining power. (In fact, in order to create at least a slight incentive for person 2 to agree to trade to the identified point, the point would have to be slightly inside the lens.)
 
In order to trace out the entire contract curve, the above optimization problem can be modified as follows. Maximize a weighted average of the utilities of persons 1 and 2, with weights ''b'' and 1 – ''b'', subject to the constraints that the allocations of each good not exceed its supply and subject to the constraints that both people's utilities be at least as great as their utilities at the initial endowments:
 
:<math>\max_{x_{1}^{1},x_{2}^{1},x_{1}^{2},x_{2}^{2}} b \cdot u^1(x_{1}^{1},x_{2}^{1})+ (1-b) \cdot u^2(x_{1}^{2},x_{2}^{2})</math>
 
subject to:
 
:<math>
x_{1}^{1}+x_{1}^{2} \leq \omega_{1}^{tot}
</math>
 
:<math>
x_{2}^{1}+x_{2}^{2} \leq \omega_{2}^{tot}
</math>
 
:<math>
u^1(x_{1}^{1},x_{2}^{1}) \geq u_{0}^{1}
</math>
 
:<math>
u^2(x_{1}^{2},x_{2}^{2}) \geq u_{0}^{2}
</math>
 
where <math>u^1</math> is the utility that person 1 would experience in the absence of trading away from the initial endowment. By varying the weighting parameter ''b'', one can trace out the entire contract curve: If ''b'' = 1 the problem is the same as the previous problem, and it identifies an efficient point at one edge of the lens formed by the indifference curves of the initial endowment; if ''b'' = 0 all the weight is on person 2's utility instead of person 1's, and so the optimization identifies the efficient point on the other edge of the lens. As ''b'' varies smoothly between these two extremes, all the in-between points on the contract curve are traced out.
 
Note that the above optimizations are not ones that the two people would actually engage in, either explicitly or implicitly. Instead, these optimizations are simply a way for the economist to identify points on the contract curve.
 
==See also==
*[[Welfare economics]]
*[[List of economics topics]].
 
==References==
*[[Andreu Mas-Colell|Mas-Colell, Andreu]]; Whinston, Michael D.; & Green, Jerry (1995). ''Microeconomic Theory''. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-510268-1
 
[[Category:Welfare economics]]
[[Category:Economics curves]]

Latest revision as of 23:16, 17 July 2014

Roberto is what's written located on his birth certificate he never really adored that name. South Carolina is its birth place. The favourite hobby for him and moreover his kids is to fish and he's previously been doing it for a long time. Auditing is how he supports the puppy's family. Go of his website to come out more: http://circuspartypanama.com

Also visit my webpage clash of clans cheat, Highly recommended Site,