CCFL inverter: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
en>Carel.jonkhout
edited two awkward sentences
 
en>Materialscientist
Reverted 1 good faith edit by 180.190.10.3 using STiki
Line 1: Line 1:
== a decision of the future ==
[[File:Isoquant_isocost_graph.gif|thumb|500px|right|Isocost v. Isoquant Graph]]


Must be just before the start of all stereotypes never set architecture,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_0.htm スポーツサングラス オークリー], once the chaos began airflow into force ten basic rules of time and space,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_54.htm オークリー 度付きサングラス], then it is no architecture chance. Any super strong ...... only once in a long lifetime opportunity structure.<br><br>this architecture,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_44.htm オークリー サングラス 野球].<br><br>a decision of the future, the future of the small universe evolve.<br><br>two,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_77.htm オークリー ゴルフ サングラス], decided to source a small universe!<br><br>Third,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_66.htm オークリー サングラス レディース], determine the strong can achieve the ultimate.<br><br>This is like the most basic framework to build the foundations of a skyscraper when foundations play well, naturally made no skyscrapers come. If you do not do a good job this universe architecture ...... gradually evolve a small universe of the future will also have limits,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_15.htm オークリー サングラス アウトレット], such as Evolution to 'eternal God stage' can not break it.<br><br>let your own sentiment already high level, can not evolve to enhance small universe, it would never be able to break through.<br><br>How can this step lightly,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_65.htm ゴルフ サングラス オークリー]?<br><br>,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_43.htm オークリー サングラス ランニング]......<br><br>Luo Feng
In [[economics]] an '''isocost''' line shows all combinations of inputs which cost the same total amount.<ref>Varian, Hal R., ''Microeconomic Analysis'', third edition, Norton, 1992.</ref><ref>Chiang, Alpha C., ''Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics'', third edition, McGraw-Hill, 1984.</ref> Although similar to the [[budget constraint]] in [[consumer theory]], the use of the isocost line pertains to cost-minimization in production, as opposed to utility-maximization. For the two production [[factors of production|inputs]] labour and capital, with fixed unit costs of the inputs, the equation of the isocost line is
相关的主题文章:
:<math>rK+wL = C\,</math>
<ul>
 
  <li>[http://210.40.3.56/plus/feedback.php?aid=8 http://210.40.3.56/plus/feedback.php?aid=8]</li>
 
  <li>[http://www.tjhxdy.com/plus/feedback.php?aid=15 http://www.tjhxdy.com/plus/feedback.php?aid=15]</li>
 
  <li>[http://club.huangdaobook.com/home.php?mod=space&uid=107715 http://club.huangdaobook.com/home.php?mod=space&uid=107715]</li>
 
</ul>


== women could not help but shed tears uncontrollably. ==
where w represents the wage rate of labour, r represents the rental rate of capital, K is the amount of capital used, L is the amount of labour used, and C is the total cost of acquiring those quantities of the two inputs.  


Ocean waters, to deal with the other end Devourer,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_19.htm オークリー サングラス 手入れ], Yelena,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_17.htm 登山 サングラス オークリー], take care of yourself. 'Sokolov and blast out loud, he stared at the doors and windows of the house, and that people palpitations eyes has a hint of hope, desire.<br><br>However,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_5.htm オークリー 野球用サングラス], there has been no open windows and doors.<br><br>Sokolov suddenly turned around,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_10.htm オークリー サングラス 野球].<br><br>strode directly toward not far from a saucer-shaped smart fighter, and soon, UFO voice sounded fighters began to take off.<br><br>cracking!<br><br>finally opened the door of the house, and an apron for women looked at carefully, but only saw a small UFO distant sky,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_59.htm オークリー サングラス フラックジャケット], and soon disappeared in the horizon warplanes flying saucer.<br><br>looked at the snow on the ground that the large footprints, women could not help but shed tears uncontrollably.<br><br>,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_17.htm 登山 サングラス オークリー]......<br><br>brutal polar bear 'Sokolov' farewell to his daughter,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_12.htm オークリー サングラスケース].<br><br>snow Great 'Mohandesen' farewell to his wife,[http://www.alleganycountyfair.org/_vti_cnf/rakuten_oakley_1.htm オークリーのサングラス], son and grandson just drink milk.<br><br>Lion King 'Tripathi ·
The absolute value of the slope of the isocost line, with capital plotted vertically and labour plotted horizontally, equals the ratio of unit costs of labour and capital.  The slope is:
相关的主题文章:
 
<ul>
:<math>-w/r. \,</math>
 
 
  <li>[http://xyssygz.com/bbs/home.php?mod=space&uid=252192 http://xyssygz.com/bbs/home.php?mod=space&uid=252192]</li>
The isocost line is combined with the [[isoquant]] map to determine the optimal production point at any given level of output. Specifically, the point of tangency between any isoquant and an isocost line gives the lowest-cost combination of inputs that can produce the level of output associated with that isoquant.  Equivalently, it gives the maximum level of output that can be produced for a given total cost of inputs. A line joining tangency points of isoquants and isocosts (with input prices held constant) is called the [[expansion path]].<ref name="Salvatore">Salvatore, Dominick (1989). ''Schaum's outline of theory and problems of managerial economics,'' McGraw-Hill, ISBN 978-0-07-054513-7</ref>
 
 
  <li>[http://annamariyaarts.com/blogs/post/8239 http://annamariyaarts.com/blogs/post/8239]</li>
==The cost-minimization problem==
 
 
  <li>[http://www.zzzsw.com/plus/view.php?aid=506197 http://www.zzzsw.com/plus/view.php?aid=506197]</li>
The cost-minimization problem of the firm is to choose an input bundle (''K'',''L'') feasible for the output level ''y'' that costs as little as possible. A cost-minimizing input bundle is a point on the isoquant for the given ''y'' that is on the lowest possible isocost line. Put differently, a cost-minimizing input bundle must satisfy two conditions:
 
 
</ul>
# it is on the ''y''-isoquant
# no other point on the ''y''-isoquant is on a lower isocost line.
 
==The case of smooth isoquants convex to the origin==
 
If the ''y''-isoquant is smooth and convex to the origin and the cost-minimizing bundle involves a positive amount of each input, then at a cost-minimizing input bundle an isocost line is tangent to the ''y''-isoquant.
Now since the absolute value of the slope of the isocost line is the input cost ratio <math>w/r</math>, and the absolute value of the slope of an isoquant is the [[marginal rate of technical substitution]] (MRTS), we reach the following conclusion:
If the isoquants are smooth and convex to the origin and the cost-minimizing input bundle involves a positive amount of each input, then this bundle satisfies the following two conditions:
 
* It is on the ''y''-isoquant (i.e. ''F''(''K'', ''L'') = ''y'' where ''F'' is the [[production function]]), and
 
* the MRTS at (''K'', ''L'') equals ''w''/''r''.
 
The condition that the MRTS be equal to ''w''/''r'' can be given the following intuitive interpretation. We know that the MRTS is equal to the ratio of the marginal products of the two inputs. So the condition that the MRTS be equal to the input cost ratio is equivalent to the condition that the marginal product per dollar is equal for the two inputs. This condition makes sense: at a particular input combination, if an extra dollar spent on input 1 yields more output than an extra dollar spent on input 2, then more of input 1 should be used and less of input 2, and so that input combination cannot be optimal. Only if a dollar spent on each input is equally productive is the input bundle optimal.
 
==References==
<references/>
 
[[Category:Microeconomics]]
[[Category:Costs]]
[[Category:Production economics]]

Revision as of 10:54, 3 November 2013

File:Isoquant isocost graph.gif
Isocost v. Isoquant Graph

In economics an isocost line shows all combinations of inputs which cost the same total amount.[1][2] Although similar to the budget constraint in consumer theory, the use of the isocost line pertains to cost-minimization in production, as opposed to utility-maximization. For the two production inputs labour and capital, with fixed unit costs of the inputs, the equation of the isocost line is

where w represents the wage rate of labour, r represents the rental rate of capital, K is the amount of capital used, L is the amount of labour used, and C is the total cost of acquiring those quantities of the two inputs.

The absolute value of the slope of the isocost line, with capital plotted vertically and labour plotted horizontally, equals the ratio of unit costs of labour and capital. The slope is:

The isocost line is combined with the isoquant map to determine the optimal production point at any given level of output. Specifically, the point of tangency between any isoquant and an isocost line gives the lowest-cost combination of inputs that can produce the level of output associated with that isoquant. Equivalently, it gives the maximum level of output that can be produced for a given total cost of inputs. A line joining tangency points of isoquants and isocosts (with input prices held constant) is called the expansion path.[3]

The cost-minimization problem

The cost-minimization problem of the firm is to choose an input bundle (K,L) feasible for the output level y that costs as little as possible. A cost-minimizing input bundle is a point on the isoquant for the given y that is on the lowest possible isocost line. Put differently, a cost-minimizing input bundle must satisfy two conditions:

  1. it is on the y-isoquant
  2. no other point on the y-isoquant is on a lower isocost line.

The case of smooth isoquants convex to the origin

If the y-isoquant is smooth and convex to the origin and the cost-minimizing bundle involves a positive amount of each input, then at a cost-minimizing input bundle an isocost line is tangent to the y-isoquant. Now since the absolute value of the slope of the isocost line is the input cost ratio , and the absolute value of the slope of an isoquant is the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS), we reach the following conclusion: If the isoquants are smooth and convex to the origin and the cost-minimizing input bundle involves a positive amount of each input, then this bundle satisfies the following two conditions:

  • the MRTS at (K, L) equals w/r.

The condition that the MRTS be equal to w/r can be given the following intuitive interpretation. We know that the MRTS is equal to the ratio of the marginal products of the two inputs. So the condition that the MRTS be equal to the input cost ratio is equivalent to the condition that the marginal product per dollar is equal for the two inputs. This condition makes sense: at a particular input combination, if an extra dollar spent on input 1 yields more output than an extra dollar spent on input 2, then more of input 1 should be used and less of input 2, and so that input combination cannot be optimal. Only if a dollar spent on each input is equally productive is the input bundle optimal.

References

  1. Varian, Hal R., Microeconomic Analysis, third edition, Norton, 1992.
  2. Chiang, Alpha C., Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics, third edition, McGraw-Hill, 1984.
  3. Salvatore, Dominick (1989). Schaum's outline of theory and problems of managerial economics, McGraw-Hill, ISBN 978-0-07-054513-7