COSMO Solvation Model: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
English corrections
 
en>SporkBot
m Replace template per TFD outcome; no change in content
Line 1: Line 1:
The individual who wrote the post is known as Jayson Hirano and he totally digs that title. For a whilst I've been in Alaska but I will have to move in a yr or two. One of [http://www.sirudang.com/siroo_Notice/2110 good psychic] the very best things in the globe for him is doing ballet and he'll be starting some thing else along with it. Office supervising is exactly where her main earnings arrives from.<br><br>my web-site - tarot card [http://bigpolis.com/blogs/post/6503 online psychic readings] ([http://si.dgmensa.org/xe/index.php?document_srl=48014&mid=c0102 recommended site])
{{multiple issues|
{{Unreferenced|date=December 2006}}
{{Expert-subject|Economics|date=November 2008}}
}}
 
In two-sector [[macroeconomics|macroeconomic]] models, a '''Harrod–Johnson diagram''' is a way of visualizing the relationship between the output price ratios, the input price ratios, and the endowment ratio of the two goods. Often the goods are a consumption and investment good, and this diagram shows what will happen to the price ratio if the endowment changes.  The diagram juxtaposes a graph which has input price ratios as its horizontal axis, endowment ratios as its positive vertical axis, and output price ratios as its negative vertical axis.  This may seem unintuitive, but by doing this, it is easier to see the relationship between the output price ratios and the endowmentThe diagram is named after economists, [[Roy F. Harrod]] and [[Harry G. Johnson]].
 
==Derivation==
[[Image:Harrod-Johnson diagram.png|frame|right|Harrod–Johnson diagram with linear relationship between <math>k_i</math> and <math>\omega</math> and increasing relationship between ''p'' and <math>\omega</math>. Here increasing the endowment causes the price ratios to increase.]]
If we let our good 1 be an investment good, governed by the equation
<math>Y_1=F_1(K,L)\,</math>
 
and good 2 be a consumption good:
<math>Y_s=F_s(K,L)\,</math>
 
To calculate rental and wage rates, we optimize a representative firm's profit function, giving
<math>p_1 D_K[F_1(K,L)]=r=p_2 D_K[F_2(K,L)]\,</math> for the rental rate of capital, ''r'', and
<math>p_1 D_L[F_1(K,L)]=w=p_2 D_L[F_2(K,L)]\,</math> for the wage rate of labor, ''w''.
 
so the input price ratio, <math>\omega</math> is
<math>\omega=w/r=\frac{p_i D_L[F_i(K,L)],p_i D_K[F_i(K,L)]}\,</math> for <math>i=\{1,2\}</math>
Normalizing this equation by letting <math>k_i = K_i/L_i</math>, and solving for <math>k_i</math> gives us the formulas to be graphed in the first quadrant.
 
On the other hand, normalizing the equation
<math>p_1 D_K[F_1(K,L)]=p_2 D_K[F_2(K,L)]\,</math> (or <math>p_1 D_L[F_1(K,L)]=p_2 D_L[F_2(K,L)]\,</math>, which is presumably equivalent),
and solving for the price ratio, <math>p_1/P_2</math> gives the formula which is to be graphed in the fourth quadrant.
 
With these three functions graphed together, we can see our relationship.
 
{{DEFAULTSORT:Harrod-Johnson Diagram}}
[[Category:Macroeconomics]]

Revision as of 02:52, 3 September 2013

Template:Multiple issues

In two-sector macroeconomic models, a Harrod–Johnson diagram is a way of visualizing the relationship between the output price ratios, the input price ratios, and the endowment ratio of the two goods. Often the goods are a consumption and investment good, and this diagram shows what will happen to the price ratio if the endowment changes. The diagram juxtaposes a graph which has input price ratios as its horizontal axis, endowment ratios as its positive vertical axis, and output price ratios as its negative vertical axis. This may seem unintuitive, but by doing this, it is easier to see the relationship between the output price ratios and the endowment. The diagram is named after economists, Roy F. Harrod and Harry G. Johnson.

Derivation

Harrod–Johnson diagram with linear relationship between ki and ω and increasing relationship between p and ω. Here increasing the endowment causes the price ratios to increase.

If we let our good 1 be an investment good, governed by the equation Y1=F1(K,L)

and good 2 be a consumption good: Ys=Fs(K,L)

To calculate rental and wage rates, we optimize a representative firm's profit function, giving p1DK[F1(K,L)]=r=p2DK[F2(K,L)] for the rental rate of capital, r, and p1DL[F1(K,L)]=w=p2DL[F2(K,L)] for the wage rate of labor, w.

so the input price ratio, ω is ω=w/r=piDL[Fi(K,L)],piDK[Fi(K,L)] for i={1,2} Normalizing this equation by letting ki=Ki/Li, and solving for ki gives us the formulas to be graphed in the first quadrant.

On the other hand, normalizing the equation p1DK[F1(K,L)]=p2DK[F2(K,L)] (or p1DL[F1(K,L)]=p2DL[F2(K,L)], which is presumably equivalent), and solving for the price ratio, p1/P2 gives the formula which is to be graphed in the fourth quadrant.

With these three functions graphed together, we can see our relationship.