Nitric oxide synthase: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
en>Monkbot
 
en>Rjwilmsi
m iNOS: Journal cites, added 1 DOI using AWB (9904)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{About|the economic model|the computer interface|Input/output}}
Singapore residential properties are huge. The residential properties embrace landed homes equivalent to detached homes (also know as bungalows), semi-indifferent homes, terrace houses, strata-landed housing (cluster homes / townhouses), condominium residences and HDB flats.<br><br>5,000 - $eight,000 homes near the American Faculty. Homes together with bungalows near American College (pictures) Houses with swimming pools near the American College Bungalow  Semi-D Nook / Inter Terrace  Cluster House Contact us @ +sixty five 9366 2322 for Viewing or Itemizing Information Private residential property costs rose 1.8% (1.1% in real phrases) q-q in This autumn 2012, in line with the URA. These market-cooling measures have been efficient, as evidenced by the slower property price rises. There has additionally been a drop in brief-time period hypothesis (as indicated by an 18% y-y decline in sub-gross sales in This autumn 2012) and a fall in the proportion of personal residential properties bought by foreigners and corporations (7% in Q3 2012, down from 20% in This autumn 2011). Conservation Shop Houses for sale!<br><br>Find your dream worldwide and Singapore property on the market in Singapore's leading property portal – PrizedRealty.com. Latest and latest launches in Singapore, Malaysia, London, Australia, Philippines, Thailand and Cambodia. Singapore market specialists provide a summary of the outlook for our local market. Estate brokers for houses, city houses, landed property, flats and condominium for sales and rentals of properties. Administration letting services for property homeowners. Real property company. Sale and buy of property. one hundred ninety Lorong 6 Toa Payoh, #03-512 Toa Payoh Purchasing Centre, Singapore 310190. Developer of recent properties. eight Shenton Way, #21-01 Temasek Tower, Singapore 068811. Property developers. 501 Orchard Highway, #11-01 Wheelock Place, Singapore 238880. HDB Flat<br><br>Replenish a contact kind to get an prompt entry to best of Singapore actual estate. Singapore has a dynamic property market and we carry you the most complete and up-to-date on the market listings that will help you make your investment determination. Prospective Property buyers also needs to consult our property info resources, market information and historic transaction prices. Singapore new launches, new Landed Home, Cluster House, Condominium, Condominium, Commercial Industrial Properties for Sale New Projects Launched ! Simply click on > B uying E nquiry just below this annoucement to register your interest with us for selection units booking. You'll be able to download Web site Plans and Ground Plans from Learn More under New Launch Projects. Commercial / Industrial property for Rent Agent Fee<br><br>Nathan Suites, PRIME Launching View Now +65 8181-7777 Freehold Prestigious District 10 Close to Future Upper Thomson MRT, Good College Tremendous Rare Freehold in Prime District Freehold stroll to Future Bencoolen MRT Freehold four minutes walk to Future MRT Almost all BOUGHT. Strata landed units obtainable. Freehold Industrial. 4-min walk to Tai Seng MRT. Freehold Doorstep to Newton MRT Interchange Educational establishments located nearby embody Anglo-Chinese language Junior College, ISS Worldwide College and Abroad Family College. Read extra Freehold Retail models alongside Balestier Primary Street, excessive visitors. District 9  Freehold  5-min Stroll to Little India MRT HDB provides gross sales of flats via three different modes How much CPF could you employ for your purchase of a HDB Flat? D22) Boon Lay / Jurong / Tuas  HDB  Frequent Room<br><br>To jot down this ebook, I went out and interviewed the top Singapore property experts, bringing to you their (and my own) invaluable insights on the best way to make your fortune investing in actual estate. It could price 1000's of dollars to get simply certainly one of these experts to seek the advice of with you on your property purchase – if you happen to might even get entry to them. The purpose of Chesney Real Estate is to cement our #1 position because the premier property company in [http://xperiencediary.com/blogs/post/33111 singapore property listing]. We will provide real property companies' from a team of skilled managers whom are dedicated to meeting our clients wants. For Lease Function Condominium for Sale Characteristic Condominium for Lease Luxury condo close to Somerset MRT Condominium For Sale – St Thomas Suites (D09) Unfurnished condominium for sale # 500 sf
{{Use dmy dates|date=June 2013}}
{{Economics sidebar}}
 
In [[economics]], an '''input–output model''' is a quantitative economic technique that represents the interdependencies between different branches of a national economy or different regional economies.<ref name="ref">Thijs Ten Raa, ''[http://books.google.bg/books?id=nu0FAvNiFhYC&printsec=frontcover#v=onepage&q&f=false Input–output economics: theory and applications: featuring Asian economies]'', World Scientific, 2009</ref> [[Wassily Leontief]] (1905–1999) is credited with developing this type of analysis and took the [[Nobel Prize in Economics]] for his development of this model.<ref name="ref"/>
 
The International Input-Output Association is dedicated to advancing knowledge in the field of input–output study, which includes "improvements in basic data, theoretical insights and modelling, and applications, both traditional and novel, of input-output techniques."
 
==Origins==
[[Francois Quesnay]] had developed a cruder version of this technique called [[Tableau économique]], and [[Léon Walras]]'s work ''Elements of Pure Economics'' on [[general equilibrium theory]] also was a forerunner and generalization of Leontief's seminal concept.
 
[[Alexander Bogdanov]] has been credited with originating the concept in a report delivered to the [[First Conference on Scientific Organization of Labour|All Russia Conference on the Scientific Organisation of Labour and Production Processes]], in January 1921.<ref name=Belykh>{{cite journal|last=Belykh|first=A. A.|title=A Note on the Origins of Input-Output Analysis and the Contribution of the Early Soviet Economists: Chayanov, Bogdanov and Kritsman|journal=Soviet Studies|date=1989|year=1989|month=July|volume=41|issue=3|pages=426-429|accessdate=14 December 2013}}</ref> This approach was also developed by L. N. Kritsman and T. F. Remington has argued that their work provided a link between Quesnay's tableau économique and the subsequent contributions by [[Vladimir Groman]] and [[Vladimir Bazarov]] to [[Gosplan]]'s method of [[material balance planning]].<ref name=Belykh></ref>
 
Wassily  Leontief's work in the input-output model was influenced by the works of the classical economists [[Karl Marx]] and [[Jean Charles Léonard de Sismondi]]. Karl Marx's economics provided an early outline involving a set of tables where the economy consisted of two interlinked departments.<ref name="Planning and the Real Origins of Input-Output Analysis, 1984">''Planning and the Real Origins of Input-Output Analysis'', by D.L. Clark 1984. Journal of Contemporary Asia. Vol. 14, Issue 4 (1984), pp. 408-429.</ref>
 
Leontief's major contribution was to simplify Walras's formulation to make the computation feasible and empirically useful. Input–output analysis assumes that input proportions between different economic sectors are fixed and do not change significantly in the short-term. As a result, results calculated by this method should be regarded only as approximations.
 
== Understanding the input–output model ==
 
An understanding of the economy as consisting of linked sectors goes back to the French economist [[François Quesnay]], and was fully developed by [[Léon Walras]] in 1874.<ref>Elements of pure economics, L. Walras</ref> However, [[Wassily Leontief]] was the first to use a [[matrix (mathematics)|matrix]] representation of a national (or regional) economy. His model depicts inter-industry relationships within an economy, showing how output from one industrial sector may become an input to another industrial sector. In the inter-industry matrix, column entries typically represent inputs to an industrial sector, while row entries represent outputs from a given sector. This format therefore shows how dependent each sector is on every other sector, both as a customer of outputs from other sectors and as a supplier of inputs. Each column of the input–output [[Matrix (mathematics)|matrix]] shows the monetary value of inputs to each sector and each row represents the value of each sector's outputs.
 
==Method of socialist planning==
{{Socialism sidebar |Ideas}}
The input-output model is one of the major conceptual models for a [[socialist]] [[planned economy]]. This model involves the direct determination of physical quantities to be produced in each industry, which is used to formulate a consistent economic plan of resource allocation. This method of planning is contrasted with price-directed [[Lange model|Lange-model socialism]] and Soviet-style material balance planning.<ref>{{ cite web | url=http://www.economictheories.org/2009/06/quantity-directed-socialism.html | title=Quantity-Directed Socialism | author=Zera | year= | work= | publisher=EconomicTheories.Org | accessdate=21 December 2013}}</ref>
 
In the economy of the [[Soviet Union]], planning was conducted using the method of material balances up until the country's dissolution. The method of material balances was first developed in the 1930s during the Soviet Union's rapid industrialization drive. Input-output planning was never adopted because the material balance system had become entrenched in the Soviet economy, and input-output planning was shunned for ideological reasons. As a result, the benefits of consistent and detailed planning through input-output analysis was never realized in the [[Analysis of Soviet-type economic planning|Soviet-type economies]].<ref>''Towards A New Socialism'', 1993, by Paul cockshott and Allin Cottrell. Coronet Books Inc. 978-0851245454. "Planning in the USSR", (P.79)</ref>
 
==Usefulness==
 
Because the input–output model is fundamentally linear in nature, it lends itself to rapid computation as well as flexibility in computing the effects of changes in demand. Input–output models for different regions can also be linked together to investigate the effects of inter-regional trade, and additional columns can be added to the table to perform environmental input–output analysis (EIOA). For example, information on fossil fuel inputs to each sector can be used to investigate flows of embodied carbon within and between different economies.
 
The structure of the input–output model has been incorporated into national accounting in many developed countries, and as such can be used to calculate important measures such as national GDP. input–output economics has been used to study regional economies within a nation, and as a tool for national and regional economic planning. A main use of input–output analysis is to measure the economic impacts of events as well as public investments or programs as shown by [[IMPLAN]] and [[RIMS-II]]. It is also used to identify economically related industry clusters and also so-called "key" or "target" industries (industries that are most likely to enhance the internal coherence of a specified economy). By linking industrial output to satellite accounts articulating energy use, effluent production, space needs, and so on, input–output analysts have extended the approaches application to a wide variety of uses.
 
==Basic derivation==
 
Say that we have an economy with <math> n </math> sectors. Each sector produces <math> x_i </math> units of a single homogeneous good. Assume that the <math> i </math>th sector, in order to produce 1 unit, must use <math> a_{ij} </math> units from sector <math> j </math>. Furthermore, assume that each sector sells some of its output to other sectors (intermediate output) and some of its output to consumers (final output, or final demand). Call final demand in the <math> i </math>th sector <math> d_i </math>. Then we might write
 
:<math>
 
x_i = a_{1i}x_1 + a_{2i}x_2 + \ldots + a_{ni}x_n + d_i,
 
</math>
 
or total output equals intermediate output plus final output. If we let <math> A </math> be the matrix of coefficients <math> a_{ij} </math>, <math> x </math> be the vector of total output, and <math> d </math> be the vector of final demand, then our expression for the economy becomes
 
:<math>
 
x = Ax + d
 
</math>
 
which after re-writing becomes <math> (I - A)x = d </math>. If the matrix <math> I - A </math> is invertible then this is a linear system of equations with a unique solution, and so given some final demand vector the required output can be found. Furthermore, if the principal [[Minor (linear algebra)|minors]] of the matrix <math> I - A </math> are all positive (known as the [[Hawkins-Simon Condition]]), the required output vector <math> x </math> is non-negative.
 
=== Example ===
 
Consider an economy with two goods, A and B. The matrix of coefficients and the final demand is given by
 
:<math>
 
A = \left(\begin{array}{cc} 0.5 & 0.2 \\ 0.4 & 0.1 \end{array}\right) \text{ and } d = \left(\begin{array}{c} 7 \\ 4 \end{array}\right).
 
</math>
 
Intuitively, this corresponds to finding the amount of output each sector should produce given that we want 7 units of good A and 4 units of good B. Then solving the system of linear equations derived above gives us
 
:<math>
 
x = (I - A)^{-1} d = \left(\begin{array}{c} 19.19 \\ 12.97 \end{array}\right).
 
</math>
 
For practical purposes it might be challenging to actually compute the inverse matrix, given that some input–output tables are in excess of hundreds of sectors.
 
=== Further research ===
 
There are many interesting aspects of the Leontief system, and there is an extensive literature. There is the Hawkins-Simon Condition on producibility. There has been interest in disaggregation to clustered inter-industry flows, and the study of constellations of industries. A great deal of empirical work has been done to identify coefficients, and data has been published for the national economy as well as for regions. This has been a healthy, exciting area for work by economists because the Leontief system can be extended to a model of general equilibrium; it offers a method of decomposing work done at a macro level.
 
=== Introducing transportation ===
 
Transportation is implicit in the notion of inter-industry flows. It is explicitly recognized when transportation is identified as an industry – how much is purchased from transportation in order to produce. But this is not very satisfactory because transportation requirements differ, depending on industry locations and capacity constraints on regional production. Also, the receiver of goods generally pays freight cost, and often transportation data are lost because transportation costs are treated as part of the cost of the goods.
 
[[Walter Isard]] and his student, [[Leon Moses]], were quick to see the spatial economy and transportation implications of input–output, and began work in this area in the 1950s developing a concept of interregional input–output. Take a one region versus the world case. We wish to know something about interregional commodity flows, so introduce a column into the table headed "exports" and we introduce an "import" row.
 
{| border="1" cellpadding="5" cellspacing="0" align="center"
|+'''Table: Adding Export And Import Transactions'''
|Economic Activities
| 1
| 2
| …
| …
| Z
| Exports
| Final Demand
| Total Outputs
|-
|1
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|-
|2
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|-
|…
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|-
|…
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|-
|Z
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|-
|Imports
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|}
 
A more satisfactory way to proceed would be to tie regions together at the industry level. That is, we could identify both intra-region inter-industry transactions and inter-region inter-industry transactions. The problem here is that the table grows quickly.
 
input–output is conceptually simple. Its extension to a model of equilibrium in the national economy is also relatively simple and attractive but requires great skill{{citation needed|date=December 2013}} and high-quality data. One who wishes to do work with input–output systems must deal skillfully with industry classification, data estimation, and inverting very large, ill-conditioned matrices. Moreover, changes in relative prices are not readily handled by this modeling approach alone. Of course, input–output accounts are part and parcel to a more flexible form of modeling, [[Computable general equilibrium]] models.
 
Two additional difficulties are of interest in transportation work. There is the question of substituting one input for another, and there is the question about the stability of coefficients as production increases or decreases. These are intertwined questions. They have to do with the nature of regional production functions.
 
== Measuring input–output tables ==
 
The mathematics of input–output economics is straightforward, but the data requirements are enormous because the expenditures and revenues of each branch of economic activity have to be represented. As a result, not all countries collect the required data and data quality varies, even though a set of standards for the data's collection has been set out by the United Nations through its System of National Accounts (SNA):<ref>[http://unstats.un.org/unsd/nationalaccount/sna.asp About SNA], UN</ref> the most recent standard is the 2008 SNA. Because the data collection and preparation process for the input–output accounts is necessarily labor and computer intensive, input–output tables are often published long after the year in which the data were collected—typically as much as 5–7 years after. Moreover, the economic "snapshot" that the benchmark version of the tables provides of the economy's cross-section is typically taken only once every few years, at best.
 
However, many developed countries estimate input–output accounts annually and with much greater recency. This is because while most uses of the input–output analysis focus on the matrix set of interindustry exchanges, the actual focus of the analysis from the perspective of most national statistical agencies is the [[benchmarking]] of [[gross domestic product]]. input–output tables therefore are an instrumental part of [[national accounts]]. As suggested above, the core input–output table reports only intermediate goods and services that are exchanged among industries. But an array of row [[vector (geometric)|vector]]s, typically aligned below this matrix, record non-industrial inputs by industry like payments for labor; indirect business taxes; dividends, interest, and rents; capital consumption allowances (depreciation); other property-type income (like profits); and purchases from foreign suppliers (imports). At a national level, although excluding the imports, when summed this is called "gross product originating" or "gross domestic product by industry." Another array of column vectors is called "final demand" or "gross product product consumed." This displays columns of spending by households, governments, changes in industry stocks, and industries on investment, as well as net exports. (See also Gross domestic product.) In any case, by employing the results of an economic census which asks for the sales, payrolls, and material/equipment/service input of each establishment, statistical agencies back into estimates of industry-level profits and investments using the input–output matrix as a sort of double-accounting framework.
 
==Input–output analysis versus consistency analysis==
Despite the clear ability of the input-output model to depict and analyze the dependence of one industry or sector on another, Leontief and others never managed to introduce the full spectrum of dependency relations in a market economy. In 2003, Mohammad Gani [http://sb.iub.edu.bd/Dr_Mohammad_Osman_Gani.html], a pupil of Leontief, introduced [[consistency analysis]] in his book 'Foundations of Economic Science' (ISBN 984320655X), which formally looks exactly like the input–output table but explores the dependency relations in terms of payments and intermediation relations. Consistency analysis explores the consistency of plans of buyers and sellers by decomposing the input–output table into four matrices, each for a different kind of means of payment. It integrates micro and macroeconomics in one model and deals with money in an ideology-free manner. It deals with the flow of funds via the movement of goods.
 
== See also ==
 
* [[Computable general equilibrium]]
* [[Economic base analysis]]
* [[Economic planning]]
* [[EIOLCA]]
* [[Gross Output]]
* [[Industrial organization]]
* [[IPO Model]]
* [[Material balance planning]]
* [[Net output]]
* [[Socialist economics]]
* [[Shift-share analysis]]
 
== References ==
{{reflist|colwidth=30em}}
 
==Bibliography==
*  Dietzenbacher, Erik and Michael L. Lahr, eds. ''Wassilly Leontief and Input-Output Economics''. Cambridge University Press, 2004.
*  Isard, Walter et al. ''Methods of Regional Analysis: An Introduction to Regional Science.'' MIT Press 1960.
* Isard, Walter and Thomas W. Langford. ''Regional Input-Output Study: Recollections, Reflections, and Diverse Notes on the Philadelphia Experience.'' The MIT Press. 1971.
*  Lahr, Michael L. and Erik Dietzenbacher, eds. ''Input-Output Analysis: Frontiers and Extensions.'' Palgrave, 2001.
*  Leontief, Wassily W. ''Input-Output Economics.'' 2nd ed., New York: Oxford University Press, 1986.
*  Miller, Ronald E. and Peter D. Blair. ''Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions.'' Prentice Hall, 1985.
*  Miller, Ronald E. and Peter D. Blair. ''Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions,'' 2nd edition. Cambridge University Press, 2009.
*  Miller, Ronald E., Karen R. Polenske, and Adam Z. Rose, eds. ''Frontiers of Input-Output Analysis.'' N.Y.: Oxford UP, 1989.[HB142 F76 1989/ Suzz]
*  Miernyk, William H. ''The Elements of Input-Output Anaysis,'' 1965.[http://www.rri.wvu.edu/WebBook/Miernykweb/new/index.htm].
*  Polenske, Karen. ''Advances in Input-Output Analysis.'' 1976.
* Pokrovskii, Vladimir N. [http://www.springer.com/physics/complexity/book/978-94-007-2095-4 ''Econodynamics. The Theory of Social Production''], Springer, Dordrecht, Heidelberg et cetera, 2011.
*  ten Raa, Thijs. ''The Economics of Input-Output Analysis.'' Cambridge University Press, 2005.
*  US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis . ''Regional multipliers: A user handbook for regional input-output modeling system (RIMS II)''. Third edition. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. 1997.
 
==External links==
* [http://www.iioa.org International Input-Output Association]
* [http://www2.sjsu.edu/faculty/watkins/inputoutput.htm Input-Output Analysis and Related Methods], San José State University
* [http://www.doingbusiness.org/ Doing Business project input/output tables for reforms]
* Energy Economics. Input-Output Analysis: [https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=onIhwmbL8CA Lecture – 6] and [https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=CTt4y8bokWs Lecture 7] – two introductory videos on Input-Output methodology with a focus on energy economics from [[Indian Institute of Technology Kharagpur|IIT Kharagpur]].
 
{{DEFAULTSORT:Input-output model}}
[[Category:Economics models]]
[[Category:Economic planning]]
[[Category:National accounts]]
[[Category:Urban, rural, and regional economics]]
[[Category:Regional science]]

Revision as of 19:25, 14 February 2014

Singapore residential properties are huge. The residential properties embrace landed homes equivalent to detached homes (also know as bungalows), semi-indifferent homes, terrace houses, strata-landed housing (cluster homes / townhouses), condominium residences and HDB flats.

5,000 - $eight,000 homes near the American Faculty. Homes together with bungalows near American College (pictures) Houses with swimming pools near the American College Bungalow Semi-D Nook / Inter Terrace Cluster House Contact us @ +sixty five 9366 2322 for Viewing or Itemizing Information Private residential property costs rose 1.8% (1.1% in real phrases) q-q in This autumn 2012, in line with the URA. These market-cooling measures have been efficient, as evidenced by the slower property price rises. There has additionally been a drop in brief-time period hypothesis (as indicated by an 18% y-y decline in sub-gross sales in This autumn 2012) and a fall in the proportion of personal residential properties bought by foreigners and corporations (7% in Q3 2012, down from 20% in This autumn 2011). Conservation Shop Houses for sale!

Find your dream worldwide and Singapore property on the market in Singapore's leading property portal – PrizedRealty.com. Latest and latest launches in Singapore, Malaysia, London, Australia, Philippines, Thailand and Cambodia. Singapore market specialists provide a summary of the outlook for our local market. Estate brokers for houses, city houses, landed property, flats and condominium for sales and rentals of properties. Administration letting services for property homeowners. Real property company. Sale and buy of property. one hundred ninety Lorong 6 Toa Payoh, #03-512 Toa Payoh Purchasing Centre, Singapore 310190. Developer of recent properties. eight Shenton Way, #21-01 Temasek Tower, Singapore 068811. Property developers. 501 Orchard Highway, #11-01 Wheelock Place, Singapore 238880. HDB Flat

Replenish a contact kind to get an prompt entry to best of Singapore actual estate. Singapore has a dynamic property market and we carry you the most complete and up-to-date on the market listings that will help you make your investment determination. Prospective Property buyers also needs to consult our property info resources, market information and historic transaction prices. Singapore new launches, new Landed Home, Cluster House, Condominium, Condominium, Commercial Industrial Properties for Sale New Projects Launched ! Simply click on > B uying E nquiry just below this annoucement to register your interest with us for selection units booking. You'll be able to download Web site Plans and Ground Plans from Learn More under New Launch Projects. Commercial / Industrial property for Rent Agent Fee

Nathan Suites, PRIME Launching View Now +65 8181-7777 Freehold Prestigious District 10 Close to Future Upper Thomson MRT, Good College Tremendous Rare Freehold in Prime District Freehold stroll to Future Bencoolen MRT Freehold four minutes walk to Future MRT Almost all BOUGHT. Strata landed units obtainable. Freehold Industrial. 4-min walk to Tai Seng MRT. Freehold Doorstep to Newton MRT Interchange Educational establishments located nearby embody Anglo-Chinese language Junior College, ISS Worldwide College and Abroad Family College. Read extra Freehold Retail models alongside Balestier Primary Street, excessive visitors. District 9 Freehold 5-min Stroll to Little India MRT HDB provides gross sales of flats via three different modes How much CPF could you employ for your purchase of a HDB Flat? D22) Boon Lay / Jurong / Tuas HDB Frequent Room

To jot down this ebook, I went out and interviewed the top Singapore property experts, bringing to you their (and my own) invaluable insights on the best way to make your fortune investing in actual estate. It could price 1000's of dollars to get simply certainly one of these experts to seek the advice of with you on your property purchase – if you happen to might even get entry to them. The purpose of Chesney Real Estate is to cement our #1 position because the premier property company in singapore property listing. We will provide real property companies' from a team of skilled managers whom are dedicated to meeting our clients wants. For Lease Function Condominium for Sale Characteristic Condominium for Lease Luxury condo close to Somerset MRT Condominium For Sale – St Thomas Suites (D09) Unfurnished condominium for sale # 500 sf