Jacobi sum: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
en>Bender235
m References: Typo fixing, typos fixed: , → , (2) using AWB
 
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
Hello and welcome. My title is Figures Wunder. My day occupation is a meter reader. One of the extremely best things in the world for me is to do aerobics and now I'm attempting to earn money with it. For many years he's been residing in North Dakota and his family enjoys it.<br><br>Also visit my website :: [http://www.ninfeta.tv/blog/99493 std testing at home]
In [[game theory]], a '''repeated game''' ('''supergame''' or '''iterated game''') is an [[extensive form game]] which consists in some number of repetitions of some base game (called a '''stage game''').  The stage game is usually one of the well-studied [[list of games in game theory|2-person games]]. It captures the idea that a player will have to take into account the impact of his current action on the future actions of other players; this is sometimes called his reputation.  The presence of different [[Nash equilibrium|equilibrium]] properties is because the threat of retaliation is real, since one will play the game again with the same person. It can be proved that every strategy that has a payoff greater than the minmax payoff can be a [[Nash equilibrium|Nash Equilibrium]], which is a very large set of strategies. ''Single stage game'' or ''single shot game'' are names for non-repeated games.
 
==Finitely vs infinitely repeated games==
Repeated games may be broadly divided into two classes, depending on whether the horizon is finite or infinite. The results in these two cases are very different. Even finitely repeated games are not necessarily finite horizon, the player may just perceive a probability of another cycle and act accordingly. For example, the fact that everyone has a fixed lifetime doesn't mean that all games should be finite horizon. Also, players might act differently when the horizon is far away as opposed to when it is close by, which can probably be thought of as a time modifier function applied to the payoff. The difference in strategies for finite versus infinite horizon games is a hotly debated topic, and many game theorists have differing views regarding it.
 
==Infinitely repeated games==
 
The most widely studied repeated games are games that are repeated a possibly infinite number of times. On many occasions, it is found that the optimal method of playing a repeated game is not to repeatedly play a Nash strategy of the constituent game (look at the Repeated prisoner's dilemma example), but to cooperate and play a socially optimum strategy. This can be interpreted as a "social norm" and one essential part of infinitely repeated games is punishing players who deviate from this cooperative strategy. The punishment may be something like playing a strategy which leads to reduced payoff to both players for the rest of the game (called a trigger strategy). There are many results in theorems which deal with how to achieve and maintain a socially optimal equilibrium in repeated games. These results are collectively called [[Folk theorem (game theory)|''"Folk Theorems"'']]. An important feature of a repeated game is the way in which a player's preferences may be modeled.
There are many different ways in which a preference relation may be modeled in an infinitely repeated game, the main ones are :
*Discounting - valuation of the game diminishes with time depending on the discount parameter <math>\delta</math>
*Limit of means - can be thought of as an average over T periods as T approaches infinity. <math>\lim_{T\to\infty}\sum_{t=1}^T \frac{1}{T}(v_i^t) > 0</math>
*Overtaking - Sequence <math>v_i^t</math> is superior to sequence <math>w_i^t</math>
 
==Finitely repeated games==
 
As explained earlier, finite games can be divided into two broad classes. In the first class of finitely repeated games where the time period is fixed and known, it is optimal to play the Nash strategy in the last period. When the Nash Equilibrium payoff is equal to the minmax payoff, then the player has no reason to stick to a socially optimum strategy and is free to play a selfish strategy throughout, since the punishment cannot affect him (being equal to the minmax payoff). This deviation to a selfish Nash Equilibrium strategy is explained by the [[Chainstore paradox]]. The second class of finitely repeated games are usually thought of as infinitely repeated games.
 
==Repeated prisoner's dilemma==
 
Although the [[Prisoner's dilemma]] has only one [[Nash equilibrium]] (everyone defect), cooperation can be sustained in the repeated Prisoner's dilemma if the discount factor is not too low; that is, if the players are interested enough in future outcomes of the game.  Strategies known as [[Trigger strategy|trigger strategies]] comprise Nash equilibria of the repeated Prisoner's dilemma. However, Prisoner's dilemma is one where the minmax value is equal to the Nash Equilbrium payoff. This means that a player who knows the exact horizon may just decide to switch to Defect without fear of punishment.
 
An example of repeated prisoner's dilemma is the WWI  trench warfare. Here, though initially it was best to cause as much damage to the other party as possible, as time passed and the opposing parties got to 'know' each other, they realised that causing as much damage as possible to the other by, e.g. artillery will only prompt a similar response: e.g. blowing up the foodstock of the other (through bombardment) will only leave both battalions hungry. After some time, the opposing battalions learned that it is sufficient to ''show'' what they are capable of, instead of actually carrying out the act.{{Citation needed|date=January 2013}}
 
==Solving repeated games==
 
Complex repeated games can be solved using various techniques most of which rely heavily on [[linear algebra]] and the concepts expressed in [[fictitious play]].
 
==Incomplete information==
Repeated games can include incomplete information. Repeated games with incomplete information, were pioneered by Aumann and Maschler.<ref>Aumann, R. J., and Maschler, M. 1995. ''Repeated Games with Incomplete Information''.
Cambridge London: MIT Press [http://books.google.co.jp/books?id=xaa7xZ-WGBsC&printsec=frontcover&dq=editions:hbtf5ZKpSekC&hl=en&sa=X&ei=D4zGT6SNDeudmQXrtuyuBQ&ved=0CDcQ6AEwAQ#v=onepage&q=editions%3Ahbtf5ZKpSekC&f=false]</ref> While it is easier to treat situation where one player is informed the other not, and when information received by each player is independent, it is possible to deal with zero-sum games with incomplete information on both sides and signals are not independent.<ref>
Mertens J-F (1987) Repeated games. In: Proceedings of the international congress of mathematicians,
Berkeley 1986. American Mathematical Society, Providence, pp 1528–1577</ref>
 
== References ==
{{Reflist}}
*{{cite book |last=Fudenberg |first=Drew |authorlink2=Jean Tirole |first2=Jean |last2=Tirole |year=1991 |title=Game Theory |location=Cambridge |publisher=MIT Press |isbn=0-262-06141-4 }}
*{{cite book |last=Mailath |first=G. |lastauthoramp=yes |last2=Samuelson |first2=L. |year=2006 |title=Repeated games and reputations: long-run relationships |location=New York |publisher=Oxford University Press |isbn=0-19-530079-3 }}
*{{cite book |first=Martin J. |last=Osborne |first2=Ariel |last2=Rubinstein |title=A Course in Game Theory |location=Cambridge |publisher=MIT Press |year=1994 |isbn=0-262-15041-7 }}
*{{cite book |first=Sylvain |last=Sorin |year=2002 |title=A First Course on Zero-Sum Repeated Games |publisher=Springer |location=Berlin |isbn=3-540-43028-8 }}
 
==External links==
*[http://www.dudziak.com/poker.php Game-Theoretic Solution to Poker Using Fictitious Play]
*[http://wiki.cc.gatech.edu/theory/index.php/Repeated_games Game Theory notes on Repeated games]
 
{{Game theory}}
 
[[Category:Game theory]]

Revision as of 03:04, 4 December 2012

In game theory, a repeated game (supergame or iterated game) is an extensive form game which consists in some number of repetitions of some base game (called a stage game). The stage game is usually one of the well-studied 2-person games. It captures the idea that a player will have to take into account the impact of his current action on the future actions of other players; this is sometimes called his reputation. The presence of different equilibrium properties is because the threat of retaliation is real, since one will play the game again with the same person. It can be proved that every strategy that has a payoff greater than the minmax payoff can be a Nash Equilibrium, which is a very large set of strategies. Single stage game or single shot game are names for non-repeated games.

Finitely vs infinitely repeated games

Repeated games may be broadly divided into two classes, depending on whether the horizon is finite or infinite. The results in these two cases are very different. Even finitely repeated games are not necessarily finite horizon, the player may just perceive a probability of another cycle and act accordingly. For example, the fact that everyone has a fixed lifetime doesn't mean that all games should be finite horizon. Also, players might act differently when the horizon is far away as opposed to when it is close by, which can probably be thought of as a time modifier function applied to the payoff. The difference in strategies for finite versus infinite horizon games is a hotly debated topic, and many game theorists have differing views regarding it.

Infinitely repeated games

The most widely studied repeated games are games that are repeated a possibly infinite number of times. On many occasions, it is found that the optimal method of playing a repeated game is not to repeatedly play a Nash strategy of the constituent game (look at the Repeated prisoner's dilemma example), but to cooperate and play a socially optimum strategy. This can be interpreted as a "social norm" and one essential part of infinitely repeated games is punishing players who deviate from this cooperative strategy. The punishment may be something like playing a strategy which leads to reduced payoff to both players for the rest of the game (called a trigger strategy). There are many results in theorems which deal with how to achieve and maintain a socially optimal equilibrium in repeated games. These results are collectively called "Folk Theorems". An important feature of a repeated game is the way in which a player's preferences may be modeled. There are many different ways in which a preference relation may be modeled in an infinitely repeated game, the main ones are :

  • Discounting - valuation of the game diminishes with time depending on the discount parameter δ
  • Limit of means - can be thought of as an average over T periods as T approaches infinity. limTt=1T1T(vit)>0
  • Overtaking - Sequence vit is superior to sequence wit

Finitely repeated games

As explained earlier, finite games can be divided into two broad classes. In the first class of finitely repeated games where the time period is fixed and known, it is optimal to play the Nash strategy in the last period. When the Nash Equilibrium payoff is equal to the minmax payoff, then the player has no reason to stick to a socially optimum strategy and is free to play a selfish strategy throughout, since the punishment cannot affect him (being equal to the minmax payoff). This deviation to a selfish Nash Equilibrium strategy is explained by the Chainstore paradox. The second class of finitely repeated games are usually thought of as infinitely repeated games.

Repeated prisoner's dilemma

Although the Prisoner's dilemma has only one Nash equilibrium (everyone defect), cooperation can be sustained in the repeated Prisoner's dilemma if the discount factor is not too low; that is, if the players are interested enough in future outcomes of the game. Strategies known as trigger strategies comprise Nash equilibria of the repeated Prisoner's dilemma. However, Prisoner's dilemma is one where the minmax value is equal to the Nash Equilbrium payoff. This means that a player who knows the exact horizon may just decide to switch to Defect without fear of punishment.

An example of repeated prisoner's dilemma is the WWI trench warfare. Here, though initially it was best to cause as much damage to the other party as possible, as time passed and the opposing parties got to 'know' each other, they realised that causing as much damage as possible to the other by, e.g. artillery will only prompt a similar response: e.g. blowing up the foodstock of the other (through bombardment) will only leave both battalions hungry. After some time, the opposing battalions learned that it is sufficient to show what they are capable of, instead of actually carrying out the act.Potter or Ceramic Artist Truman Bedell from Rexton, has interests which include ceramics, best property developers in singapore developers in singapore and scrabble. Was especially enthused after visiting Alejandro de Humboldt National Park.

Solving repeated games

Complex repeated games can be solved using various techniques most of which rely heavily on linear algebra and the concepts expressed in fictitious play.

Incomplete information

Repeated games can include incomplete information. Repeated games with incomplete information, were pioneered by Aumann and Maschler.[1] While it is easier to treat situation where one player is informed the other not, and when information received by each player is independent, it is possible to deal with zero-sum games with incomplete information on both sides and signals are not independent.[2]

References

43 year old Petroleum Engineer Harry from Deep River, usually spends time with hobbies and interests like renting movies, property developers in singapore new condominium and vehicle racing. Constantly enjoys going to destinations like Camino Real de Tierra Adentro.

  • 20 year-old Real Estate Agent Rusty from Saint-Paul, has hobbies and interests which includes monopoly, property developers in singapore and poker. Will soon undertake a contiki trip that may include going to the Lower Valley of the Omo.

    My blog: http://www.primaboinca.com/view_profile.php?userid=5889534
  • 20 year-old Real Estate Agent Rusty from Saint-Paul, has hobbies and interests which includes monopoly, property developers in singapore and poker. Will soon undertake a contiki trip that may include going to the Lower Valley of the Omo.

    My blog: http://www.primaboinca.com/view_profile.php?userid=5889534
  • 20 year-old Real Estate Agent Rusty from Saint-Paul, has hobbies and interests which includes monopoly, property developers in singapore and poker. Will soon undertake a contiki trip that may include going to the Lower Valley of the Omo.

    My blog: http://www.primaboinca.com/view_profile.php?userid=5889534
  • 20 year-old Real Estate Agent Rusty from Saint-Paul, has hobbies and interests which includes monopoly, property developers in singapore and poker. Will soon undertake a contiki trip that may include going to the Lower Valley of the Omo.

    My blog: http://www.primaboinca.com/view_profile.php?userid=5889534

External links

Earlier than you decide whether stainless steel cookware is worth buying, lets first discuss what stainless steel cookware is. Chrome steel is manufactured from an alloy, or a mix of metals. Mostly, basic iron with chromium, nickel or another minor metals. The chromium supplies rust safety and gives your cookware durability. The nickel supplies rust safety as effectively, and adds a elegant look. Most properly made chrome steel cookware has copper or aluminum added to the bottom of the pan or pot. That is performed to increases the ability of the pot or pan to conduct heat.
The perfect stainless-steel cookware is the principle category, but nonetheless it is divided into several subcategories primarily based on the standard and the value range. It can be confusing to choose the best chrome steel cookware out of the classes that may meet your necessities. That is where we took a step ahead to explain you all the data that will be useful for you to understand how to choose one of the best stainless steel cookware. The most effective chrome steel cookware set is manufactured from cheap to expensive and high quality constructed pots and pans.
You can find magnetic chrome steel in the layer on the outside of some quality pieces of stainless steel. This is to make it suitable with induction stovetops, which involve the use of a quickly charging electromagnetic area to warmth cookware. Excessive-quality stainless-steel, like All-Clad , makes use of three layers of steel—the austenite layer of metal on the within, ferrite steel on the skin, and a layer of aluminum sandwiched between the 2 for optimum warmth conductivity (metal alone does not conduct heat evenly). Lesser-quality stainless steel is usually just one layer of austenitic chrome steel.
Aesthetically talking, stainless steel is a smart alternative should you prefer to display or hang pots or pans. The clean, crisp look of all stainless-steel kitchenware can remodel a mishmash of cookware into a classy décor assertion. Chrome steel kettles, such as the Cuisinart Tea Kettle will mix particular person kitchenware into a cohesive and nice entity. Take into account purchasing stainless-steel utensils as well. Already acquired a stunning stainless-steel cookware collection? The Cuisinart Chef’s Assortment stainless pot rack is perhaps the of completion for a kitchen, liberating up house and making those pots and pans readily accessible. Get the stainless-steel cookware of your culinary desires at Macy’s!
Arduous-anodized aluminum cookware is likely one of the hottest varieties of materials, despite the fact that many people don't quite perceive the construction. Onerous-anodized aluminum is plain aluminum that has been processed in a collection of chemical baths charged with an electric present. The result's a fabric that has the same superior heat conductivity as aluminum but is non-reactive with acidic foods, such as tomatoes, and twice as exhausting as stainless-steel. Two drawbacks to laborious-anodized cookware are that it is not dishwasher-protected and, because it is not magnetic, it is not going to work with induction vary tops.
The enamel over steel technique creates a bit that has the warmth distribution of carbon steel and a non-reactive, low-stick floor. Such pots are much lighter than most different pots of similar measurement, are cheaper to make than stainless-steel pots, and don't have the rust and reactivity problems with cast iron or carbon steel. citation wanted Enamel over metal is ideal for big stockpots and for other giant pans used largely for water-based cooking. Because of its mild weight and simple cleanup, enamel over metal is also common for cookware used while camping. For more about stainless steel cookware reviews look at our web site. Clad aluminium or copper edit
Distinctive specialty cookware pieces served a la carte to go with any cookware set are constructed of a sturdy Stainless Steel with a brushed exterior end. Designed with an impact bonded, aluminum disk encapsulated base which distributes warmth quickly and evenly to allow precise temperature control. Handles are riveted for durability and performance. The New Specialty Cookware is compatible for all range sorts including induction. Along with the multi use operate, another distinctive characteristic is bottom to prime interior volume markings in both quarts and metric measurement; and every bit comes with a tempered glass lid, oven safe to 350°F.
Whether or not you're a cooking enthusiasts, knowledgeable chef or just cooking for your family you already know the importance of having a totally stocked kitchen. Not solely do you need the appropriate substances, however you additionally need the proper tools to get the job done. In any sort of fundamental cooking training lesson, you will learn that stainless steel is your new greatest friend with regards to kitchen cookware. What you will also study is that high quality cooking tools does not often come at a discounted price. Because of this, it is very important take good care of your cookware! Listed below are some fundamentals for chrome steel care.
To fight the uneven heating downside, most stainless steel pans are laminations of aluminum or copper on the underside to spread the heat around, and stainless steel inside the pan to provide a cooking floor that is impervious to no matter you would possibly put inside. In my expertise, this stainless-steel floor continues to be too sticky to fry on, and should you ever burn it you get a everlasting bother spot. However, sometimes a stainless steel cooking floor turns out to be useful when you can't use aluminum (see under) so I maintain some around. Choose one thing with a fairly thick aluminum layer on the underside.
Effectively, until you’re a metals professional and go inspect the factory where the steel is made to see whether or not their manufacturing process creates a pure austenite with out corrosive materials fashioned, you’re not going to know for certain whether or not the craftsmanship of your stainless is of the best quality. I believe your finest guess is to easily purchase excessive-quality stainless-steel from the beginning, from a brand with a status for good quality. But, I think I have discovered one way which you could determine if the stainless cookware you have already got is doubtlessly reactive.

  1. Aumann, R. J., and Maschler, M. 1995. Repeated Games with Incomplete Information. Cambridge London: MIT Press [1]
  2. Mertens J-F (1987) Repeated games. In: Proceedings of the international congress of mathematicians, Berkeley 1986. American Mathematical Society, Providence, pp 1528–1577